Currency disunion
Why
Europe’s leaders should think the unthinkable
The
Economist, April 7th, 2012
The
Irish left the sterling zone. The Balts escaped from the
rouble. The Czechs and Slovaks left each other. History is
littered with currency unions that broke up. Why not the euro?
Had its fathers foreseen turmoil, they might never have
embarked on currency union, at least not with today’s flawed
design.
The
founders of the euro thought they were forging a rival to the
American dollar. Instead they recreated a version of the gold
standard abandoned by their predecessors long ago. Unable to
devalue their currencies, struggling euro countries are trying
to regain competitiveness by “internal devaluation”, ie,
pushing down wages and prices. That hurts: unemployment in
Greece and Spain is above 20%. And resentment is deepening
among creditors. So why not release the yoke? The treaties may
declare the euro “irrevocable”, but treaties can be
changed. A taboo was broken last year when Germany and France
threatened to eject Greece after it proposed a referendum on
new bail–out terms.
One
reason the euro holds together is fear of financial and
economic chaos on an unprecedented scale. Another is the
impulse to defend the decades–long political investment in
the European project. So, despite many bitter words, Greece
has a second rescue. Its departure from the euro, Angela
Merkel, Germany’s chancellor, now says, would be “catastrophic”.
Yet Mrs Merkel is not ready to take the action needed to
stabilise the euro once and for all. Last week’s decision to
boost the euro’s firewall to “€800 billion” ($1.07
trillion) is less than meets the eye; the real lending power
will be €500 billion. And there is no prospect, for now, of
mutualising any part of the sovereign debt.
So
the euro zone remains vulnerable to new shocks. Markets still
worry about the risk of sovereign defaults, and of a partial
or total collapse of the euro. Common sense suggests that
leaders should think about how to manage a break–up. Some
may be doing so. But having described a split as bringing
economic Armageddon, leaders dare not be seen planning for it.
Instead,
the most open thinking is being promoted by a British think–tank
close to the Eurosceptic Conservative Party. This week Policy
Exchange announced a shortlist of five contestants for a £250,000
($400,000) prize for the best plan to manage a break–up of
the euro. It may be a sign of the magnitude of the task that
the organisers did not declare a winner; instead they asked
those on the shortlist to do more work and resubmit their
ideas. (A cartoon produced by an 11–year–old Dutch boy won
a €100 voucher.)
One
of the five entries, by Jonathan Tepper, lists 69 currency
break–ups in the past century. Most have not led to long–term
damage, he says. In fact, leaving the euro would help troubled
countries recover quickly. Drawing on the demise of the
Austro–Hungarian empire, among others, Mr Tepper sketches
out a scenario for the departure of the likes of Greece. A
surprise announcement is made over a weekend, and all deposits
are redenominated in new drachmas while banks are kept shut.
Capital controls are imposed to prevent the flight of money
abroad. For cash, Greeks at first use existing euro banknotes
defaced with ink or a stamp. These are withdrawn as drachma
notes are printed. Border checks restrict the export of
unstamped euro notes. Financial institutions are given time to
update software.
The
real problem with the euro, says Mr Tepper, is the fact that
many countries face large imbalances and high debts.
Devaluation for Greece would increase the burden of euro–denominated
debt. This would be alleviated by converting bonds issued
under Greek law to drachmas. Foreign–law bonds would be
restructured. Indeed, says Mr Tepper, default is essential to
recovery.
His
formula might be summed up by three Ds: depart, default and
devalue. Roger Bootle, another shortlisted entrant, says it
might be better to start with the departure of Germany and
other strong countries. But however it happens, any
fragmentation will create winners and losers, with many
bankruptcies and legal nightmares. Anybody involved in
cross–border activity will find that their assets and
liabilities change value. Neil Record says the sums involved
would be so large, and the litigation so ruinous, that the
best option would be to abolish the euro as soon as one
country leaves, so as to invalidate all euro contracts.
Unlike
Mr Record, who favours secrecy, in their paper Jens Nordvig
and Nick Firoozye argue that open contingency planning would
reduce uncertainty. They reckon there may be a total of €30
trillion–worth of cross–border exposure under foreign law,
including bonds, loans, derivatives and swaps. Disruption,
they say, could be minimised by converting all euro contracts
to a modified form of the European Currency Unit, the basket
of national currencies that preceded the euro. Catherine Dobbs,
the final entrant, proposes to unscramble the omelette by
splitting the euro into two (or more) zones: “yolk” and
“white”. All euros in all countries would be converted
into a fixed combination of the two. Savers would be protected,
initially at least, and capital flight to other euro–zone
countries would be deterred. Over time, the weaker yolk would
devalue against the stronger white.
Plan ahead
The
fate of the euro will probably be determined by politics as
much as economics. A debtor state may tire of internal
devaluation. A creditor may want to stop supporting others.
And any one of the euro’s 17 members may balk at the loss of
sovereignty involved in saving the currency. But the worst
outcome of a euro split would be a chaotic breakdown. An
orderly process increases the chance that it might be possible
to salvage from the wreckage other gains of European
integration, notably the single market.
So
euro–zone governments need to think the unthinkable. No self–respecting
general would refuse to plan for a predictable war, no matter
how much he dislikes the idea of fighting it.
Still
sickly: The euro zone’s illness is returning
The
German problem (again)
The
Economist, March 31st, 2012
When
the editors of the German tabloid Bild met Mario Draghi
recently they gave him a Pic kelhaube —a spiked
helmet— to remind the Italian that they had last year
depicted him in Prussian garb as the most Germanic of
candidates to run the European Central Bank. It may come in
useful: hardliners are taking shots at Mr Draghi for spraying
banks with €1 trillion ($1.3 trillion) of cheap money. This
“powerful drug” may have side–effects, he says, but it
works: “The worst is over” for the euro zone.
Don’t
be so sure. The fever has been rising again in Spain after the
government wildly overshot its deficit target last year. The
Italian prime minister, Mario Monti, expressed alarm (which he
later withdrew) that the Spanish illness might harm his own
country’s convalescence. Portugal and Ireland are in
recession, and may need second bail–outs; Greece will
probably require a third rescue (and the restructuring of
official debt).
As
fear returns, so have calls to boost the euro zone’s rescue
funds. “The mother of all firewalls should be in place,
strong enough, broad enough, deep enough, tall enough—just
big,” says Ángel Gurría, secretary–general of the OECD,
the rich–world think–tank. But Germany prefers a slow,
incremental response. The latest signal is that it will agree,
at a meeting of finance ministers in Copenhagen on March 30th
and 31st, to raise the firewall somewhat. The temporary rescue
fund, the European Financial Stability Facility (EFSF), would
be allowed to overlap with the permanent new European
Stability Mechanism (ESM), which is to be activated this
summer. By combining the two funds, perhaps only for a year,
the lending capacity could be raised from €500 billion to
about €740 billion.
This
may be enough to persuade the Chinese, the Americans and
others to allow the IMF to increase its resources, so helping
the defences, but it is hardly the overwhelming force Mr Gurría
seeks. Germany worries that reducing the pressure on weak
states will lead to complacency. “The Germans think that the
only way to make countries reform is to dangle them out of the
window,” says one diplomat. “This only reinforces the
belief in the markets that the euro zone is on the edge of
disaster.”
One
worrying sign for Germany was Spain’s partly successful
attempt to loosen its deficit target this year. Another is
growing trouble over the “fiscal compact”, a treaty signed
by 25 European Union countries to toughen budget discipline.
Ireland, with a history of awkward votes on EU treaties, holds
a referendum on May 31st. The Socialist front–runner in the
French presidential election, François Hollande, wants to
renegotiate the deal to include more focus on growth. Germany’s
opposition Social Democrats are making similar noises. In the
Netherlands the opposition Labour Party—which is supposed to
support the minority government on European issues—threatens
to block ratification if the government imposes austerity to
meet next year’s deficit target of 3% of GDP. (Ill–disciplined
countries that have received a tongue–lashing from the Dutch
are savouring the irony.)
Even
assuming all these difficulties are resolved, the fate of the
euro will remain uncertain. Raising the firewall and ratifying
the compact will address only some of the symptoms. A cure
requires “treating the whole patient”, as set out recently
in a clear–eyed paper by Jay Shambaugh for Brookings, an
American think–tank. It says the euro zone is afflicted by
three ills: a banking crisis, a sovereign–debt crisis and a
growth crisis. Dealing with one often makes the others worse.
A
big problem is that the euro zone is only partly integrated.
Its members have given up economic tools, such as currency
devaluation and monetary policy, yet lack “federal”
instruments to cope with shocks. The problem is not so much
the budget deficit (though Greece was certainly profligate) as
the net foreign borrowing by all actors, public and private (say
to finance a trade deficit). The euro zone has only small
internal transfers, and its workers tend not to move far for
work. Fiscal stimulus is impossible for most governments,
given their indebtedness. Structural reforms to promote growth
can take years to work.
So
redressing the imbalances must come through “internal
devaluation”: bringing down real wages and prices relative
to competitors. This was easier before 1991, when inflation
around the world was higher, but has rarely been achieved
since then (Hong Kong is one exception). With the ECB
determined to keep inflation at around 2%, internal
devaluation brings severe recession, even depression. And
falling GDP wrecks the debt ratio.
Mr
Shambaugh offers some advice. Deficit countries could cut
payroll taxes to reduce labour costs and raise VAT to
discourage imports; the effect would be magnified if surplus
states did the opposite. Germany could help by stimulating its
economy, or at least slowing down its budget consolidation.
The ECB could let inflation run higher, especially in Germany,
and could declare that it stands fully behind solvent
sovereigns. The EFSF/ESM could recapitalise weak banks. A
Europe–wide bank–deposit insurance scheme would help.
Mutualising part of the national debts would create a risk–free
European asset.
The
German problem (again)
All
these options ultimately run into the same obstacle: Germany.
It does not want to bear bigger liabilities, it wants to set
an example of budget discipline, it refuses to compromise its
competitiveness, it is allergic to inflation, it does not want
the ECB to print money and it thinks Eurobonds create moral
hazard.
There is little sign that
the chancellor, Angela Merkel, is ready to do much beyond
tweaking the firewall and pushing through the fiscal compact.
She talks of a future “political union”. If she really
wants to save the euro, she will have to put on a Pick elhaube
and lead the way to greater fiscal federalism.
|