After
Neoliberalism: Empire, Social Democracy, or Socialism?
by
Minqi Li
Since
the early 1980s, the leading capitalist states in North America and
Western Europe have pursued neoliberal policies and institutional changes.
The peripheral and semiperipheral states in Latin America, Africa, Asia,
and Eastern Europe, under the pressure of the leading capitalist states (primarily
the United States) and international monetary institutions (IMF and the
World Bank), have adopted “structural adjustments,” “shock therapies,”
or “economic reforms,” to restructure their economies in accordance
with the requirements of neoliberal economics.
A
neoliberal regime typically includes monetarist policies to lower
inflation and maintain fiscal balance (often achieved by reducing public
expenditures and raising the interest rate), “flexible” labor markets
(meaning removing labor market regulations and cutting social welfare),
trade and financial liberalization, and privatization. These policies are
an attack by the global ruling elites (primarily finance capital of the
leading capitalist states) on the working people of the world. Under
neoliberal capitalism, decades of social progress and developmental
efforts have been reversed. Global inequality in income and wealth has
reached unprecedented levels. In much of the world, working people have
suffered pauperization. Entire countries have been reduced to misery.
According
to United Nations’ Human Development Report, the world’s
richest 1 percent receive as much income as the poorest 57 percent. The
income gap between the richest 20 percent and the poorest 20 percent in
the world rose from 30:1 in 1960, to 60:1 in 1990, and to 74:1 in 1999,
and is projected to reach 100:1 in 2015. In 1999–2000, 2.8 billion
people lived on less than $2 a day, 840 million were undernourished, 2.4
billion did not have access to any form of improved sanitation services,
and one in every six children in the world of primary school age were not
in school. About 50 percent of the global nonagricultural labor force is
estimated to be either unemployed or underemployed.1
In
many countries, working people have suffered an absolute decline in living
standards. In the United States, the real weekly earnings of production
and nonsupervisory workers (in 1992 dollars) fell from $315 in 1973 to
$264 in 1989. After a decade of economic expansion, it reached $271 in
1999, which remained lower than the average real wage in 1962. In Latin
America, a continent that has suffered from neoliberal restructuring since
the 1970s, about 200 million people, or 46 percent of the population, live
in poverty. Between 1980 and the early 1990s (1991–1994), real wages
fell by 14 percent in Argentina, 21 percent in Uruguay, 53 percent in
Venezuela, 68 percent in Ecuador, and 73 percent in Bolivia.2
The
advocates of neoliberalism promised that the neoliberal “reforms” or
“structural adjustments” would usher in an era of unprecedented
economic growth, technological progress, rising living standards, and
material prosperity. In fact, the world economy has slowed towards
stagnation in the neoliberal era. The average annual growth rate of world
GDP declined from 4.9 percent between 1950 and 1973, to 3.0 percent
between 1973 and 1992, and to 2.7 percent between 1990 and 2001. Between
1980 and 1998, half of all the “developing countries” (including the
so-called “transition economies”) suffered from falling real per
capita GDP.3
The
global economy has been kept afloat by the debt-financed U.S. economy.
Between 1995 and 2002, the U.S. economy accounted for 96 percent of the
cumulative growth in world GDP.4
The U.S. expansion has been financed by reducing domestic savings, raising
the private sector debts to historically unprecedented levels, and running
large and ever-rising current account deficits. The process is
unsustainable. The enormous imbalances have to be corrected one way or the
other. If the United States cannot continue to generate ever-rising
current account deficits and none of the other large economies are capable
of functioning effectively as the autonomous driving force, the neoliberal
global economy will be under powerful downward pressures and exposed to
the threat of increasingly frequent and violent financial crises.
The
social and economic disasters brought about by neoliberalism have already
led to pervasive and growing popular resistance. The further deterioration
of global economic conditions might well push hundreds of millions of
people beyond the threshold of tolerance. A global rebellion against
neoliberalism and capitalism cannot be ruled out. Those who consider
themselves to be on the left, progressives or revolutionaries, should be
ready, first of all intellectually, for such a development.
Neoliberalism
and Global Stagnation
Neoliberalism
is not able to provide an institutional framework for sustained global
capital accumulation. Neoliberalism undermines and dismantles the
institutions set up to stabilize the capitalist economy and alleviate
capitalist social contradictions. The capitalist global economy is
therefore left exposed to increasingly frequent and violent financial
crises. As the editors of Monthly Review put it: “Globalization
under neoliberal regimes has meant in many ways the globalization of
stagnation tendencies and financial crisis.”5
Global
effective demand is the sum of global private consumption, global private
investment, and global government expenditures. Under neoliberalism,
global inequality has reached unprecedented levels and working people in
many parts of the world have suffered from absolute pauperization. It
follows that the purchasing power of the great majority of the world
population has fallen or grown more slowly than world output.
Private
investment in the face of global overcapacity stagnates, and private
capital turns to speculation in financial instruments. As a result of
financial liberalization, cross-border speculative capital flows have
greatly increased, raising the danger of capital flight and financial
crisis. Against such dangers, some central banks are forced to maintain
high interest rates, in effect paying a risk premium to global finance
capital. The average ratio of real interest rate to GDP growth rate in the
seven leading capitalist economies was 0.97 between 1881 and 1913, 2.40
between 1919 and 1939, 0.36 between 1946 and 1958, 0.55 between 1959 and
1971, 0.47 between 1972 and 1984, and 2.34 between 1985 and 1997. It is
worth noting that the real interest rate has been higher than the economic
growth rate only in two periods, the interwar depression years and the
neoliberal era. A ratio greater than one implies an inversion of the roles
of productive and speculative investment, and is a signal of systemic
crisis.6
Under
neoliberalism, governments have mostly pursued tight fiscal and monetary
policies, restraining public spending. With liberalized financial markets,
governments that run fiscal deficits are likely to be “punished” by
private investors who may respond with capital flight and attacks on the
currency. Therefore, governments (especially the governments of peripheral
and semiperipheral countries) are under strong pressures to maintain
fiscal balance by cutting expenditures. All neoliberal regimes seek to
limit government expenditure. To summarize, in the neoliberal era, all
three components of global effective demand are subject to strong downward
pressures and have tended to either contract or stagnate.
The
nineteenth century Marxists regarded the contradiction between socialized
production and the capitalist system of private appropriation as the basic
contradiction of capitalism. One may argue that the increasing
socialization of production has found its expressions in the rising
importance of fixed capital and the increasingly complex and interrelated
financial structures. Since Keynes, many economists have understood that
investment in fixed capital is subject to fundamental uncertainty and is
often beyond the reach of rational calculation. The growing complexity of
financial structures has greatly increased the chance that sudden
movements in investors’ confidence and psychological conditions may lead
to drastic and substantial fluctuations of investment and through
investment, the economy. To prevent capitalist economies from falling into
deep recessions or depressions, it is necessary to have a “big
government” that can function effectively as the macroeconomic
stabilizer.7
Neoliberalism,
by pursuing financial liberalization and attacking the public sector, has
significantly undermined and in some cases totally dismantled its
stabilizing functions. The neoliberal era has seen increasingly frequent
and violent financial crises. The Mexican crisis in 1995 was followed by
the Asian Crisis in 1997, the Russian and the Brazilian crises in 1998,
and the Argentine crisis in 2001. The role of the global macroeconomic
stabilizer has been played throughout by the U.S. Treasury and by U.S.
imports of goods and services increasingly in excess of U.S. exports; can
this continue?
The
U.S Financial Bubble and Imbalances
Without
a large economy capable of generating some autonomous demand, the global
economy might have already entered into a downward spiral. The U.S.
economic boom in the second half of the 1990s and its large and growing
trade deficit have functioned as counteracting forces against the
generally contractionary tendencies of neoliberalism.
The
U.S. economic boom was led by debt-financed private sector consumption and
by a burst of corporate investment in “high tech.” The private sector
financial balance (incomes less expenditures) moved from the historically
normal range of 3–4 percent of GDP to unprecedented negative territory,
reaching negative 5.5 percent by the third quarter of 2000. Household and
corporate sector debts as a percentage of GDP were at historical peaks.
Households were willing and able to borrow at such a rate because of the
great asset price bubble. Measured by indicators such as Tobin’s “Q”
(the ratio of market value of assets to replacement cost of capital) or by
reference to price-earning ratios, the U.S. stock market bubble that
reached its greatest expansion in 2000 is the most extreme in U.S.
economic history.8
When
the stock market bubble burst, corporate sector spending slowed
significantly (particularly in “high tech”). To avoid a deep recession,
the U.S. general government fiscal balance has moved from a surplus of 1.4
percent of GDP to a deficit of 4.6 percent of GDP between 2000 and 2003,
or a swing of 6 percent of GDP, and the U.S. Federal Reserve has lowered
the short-term interest rate from 6.5 percent to 1.25 percent. Despite the
dramatic loosening of fiscal and monetary policy, U.S. growth has been
sluggish and employment stagnant. These policies have in effect helped to
sustain the bubble. Household sector debt expansion has been sustained,
the stock market bubble has not been fully deflated, and a housing market
bubble is in turn approaching its peak.
The
U.S. current account deficit, largely the result of a steadily increasing
deficit in its international trade in goods and services, reached 5
percent of GDP in late 2002. For the capitalist world’s hegemonic power
to run a current account deficit on such a large scale is without
historical precedent. By contrast, on the eve of the First World War,
Britain ran current account surpluses close to 4 percent of GDP.
The
U.S. current account deficits are matched by reciprocal capital inflows
from the rest of the world. For the ever-rising U.S. current account
deficits to continue, the rest of the world must be willing to hold an
increasingly bigger proportion of their financial reserves in dollar-denominated
assets. Stephen Roach, the chief economist of Morgan Stanley, points out:
Currently,
about 75 percent of the world’s total foreign exchange reserves are held
in the form of dollar-denominated assets—more than twice America’s 32
percent share of world GDP (at market exchange rates). At the same time,
foreign investors hold about 45 percent of the outstanding volume of US
Treasury indebtedness, 35 percent of US corporate debt, and 12 percent of
US equities. All of these ratios are at or near record highs. Never before
has the world put more stock in America—both as an engine of growth and
as a store of financial value. The problem is that the math gets
exceedingly tenuous if it is projected into the future.9
Projections
of current account deficits at current rates need not go far into the
future to become “tenuous.” According to one study by the Levy
Economics Institute, under plausible assumptions, and supposing the U.S.
economy to grow at a rate sufficient to lower the unemployment rate, the
U.S. net foreign liability would reach more than 60 percent of GDP and the
current account deficits could reach 8.5–9.5 percent of GDP before 2010.
Alternative
Scenarios of Global Economic Crisis
There
are four possible ways for the unsustainable growth in the U.S. current
account deficit to be reversed. First, if the rest of the world grows more
rapidly, indeed far more rapidly, than the current growth rate of the U.S.
economy, there will be increased demand for U.S. goods and services,
allowing U.S. exports to grow more rapidly to close the gap with the
imports. Second, the U.S. current account deficit could be corrected by
contracting U.S. domestic demand. Third, the explosive growth in the
current account deficit may be corrected through adjustments in
“relative prices”—i.e., devaluation of the U.S. dollar. Finally, the
exercise of political and military power might affect the components of
the growth in the current account deficit in a manner favorable for the
United States.
There
is no prospect in the next several years of the first possibility, i.e.,
growth in the rest of the world at a significantly faster pace than
current growth in the United States. The burden shall fall on the second
and third options which, while achievable, pose immense risks.
Limiting
domestic U.S. growth, and therefore imports and the trade deficit, by
raising domestic interest rates is certainly within the theoretical
ability of U.S. policy makers. Indeed this would be the “orthodox” IMF
medicine administered to any other state on the planet were it to find
itself in anything like the U.S. current account difficulties. But the
United States is not like any other state on the planet, it is the hegemon.
No institution exists to force such medicine upon it. And for the U.S.
ruling elite, this course is not politically possible, at least at this
stage of the electoral cycle. But of even greater concern are the dangers
posed by the vast unprecedented accumulation of U.S. consumer and mortgage
debt. Absent a surge in domestic growth, which would itself aggravate the
current account difficulty, rising interest rates risk a wave of personal
bankruptcies of Great Depression proportions.
The
remaining option is dollar devaluation, and it is clear that a gradual and
controlled devaluation is the policy preferred by the U.S. Treasury, and
already being put into effect. The depreciation of the dollar makes U.S.
goods cheaper and foreign goods more expensive for U.S. households and
corporations. It helps to stimulate exports and dampen imports. However,
dollar depreciation reduces U.S. demand for foreign goods and exports
deflationary pressures to the rest of the world.
The
Asian economies (Japan, China, and Southeast Asia) together run current
account surpluses of $230–240 billion a year, or nearly half of the U.S.
current account deficits. But the Asian economies have either pegged their
currencies to the U.S. dollar or have intervened heavily to prevent
currency appreciation. This leaves the burden of adjustment almost
entirely on Europe.
The
European economy has not been able to generate any expansion in domestic
demand, and its growth has relied exclusively on exports. Europe’s
largest economy, the German economy, is in recession and such signs of
growth as exist elsewhere are weak. Dollar depreciation therefore is
particularly threatening for the European economies. Further, the Euro-area
governments are constrained by the so-called “Stability and Growth Pact”
which requires fiscal deficits no greater than 3 percent of GDP.
Financial
circles have urged the European governments to pursue “structural
reforms,” bringing labor and product market policies to U.S. standards.
“Structural reforms” will supposedly unleash productivity growth that
“in the long run,” will create conditions for vigorous demand
expansion. From the point of view of financial capitalists, for vigorous
accumulation to take place there has to be a dramatic improvement in
profitability and capitalist confidence. For the capitalists to be
confident, “structural reforms” have to take place to break the
resistance of the working class. At this moment, it is not at all clear
that the European capitalist class can decisively defeat the resistance of
the working class. But if the so-called “structural reforms” are
indeed carried out, their negative effects on domestic demand (through
further attacks on working people’s living standards) may very well
overwhelm whatever “positive” effects they may have on the “long run”
accumulation.
With
the European economy stagnating, it is inconceivable that it can absorb
enough U.S. exports to correct the U.S. current account deficit. A
correction that depends entirely on dollar depreciation would require a
catastrophic decline in the dollar’s value. By some estimates, the
dollar may need to fall by 30–50 percent. Such a decline would be
politically, economically, and psychologically unacceptable.10
If
the U.S. dollar is not going to depreciate against any other currency, why
does the current account deficit have to be corrected? If the rest of the
world’s central banks keep intervening, flooding the world with their
own currencies (euros, Japanese yens, and the Chinese renminbi) to prevent
dollar depreciation, why cannot the United States run an ever-larger
current account deficit for an indefinite period of time? It cannot go on
indefinitely because the rising U.S. current account deficits absorb a
growing proportion of the global saving. A theoretical limit will be
reached when the entire world’s saving is exhausted to finance the U.S.
current account deficit. But the practical limit will be reached long
before the theoretical limit. This course would raise U.S. and Japanese
government debt to astronomical levels. These gigantic government debts
would exist along with enormous household and corporate debts in the
United States and Europe.11
How
can these debts be financed? There are two possibilities. First, a global
depression and widespread household and corporate bankruptcies may destroy
much of the private debts. This is the historical solution that has
obtained in all prior systemic crises of capitalism. In theory, as debt is
devalued the conditions for a new cycle of capitalist accumulation on an
even higher level gradually come to exist. But in the last such global
depression such spontaneous recovery was inadequate, for reasons inherent
in monopoly capital that are even stronger today. This option therefore
supposes an extended period of depression. Whatever the outcome on this
hypothesis one thing is certain, neoliberalism would be dead for a very
long time, if not forever.
Secondly,
the enormous private and public sector debts could be inflated away, that
is, financed by printing money. Given the magnitude of the enormous debts
to be inflated away, the inflation strategy may send the global economy
into vicious cycles of hyperinflation and skyrocketing interest rates. If
there is any one option ruled out by all of the various global ruling
classes, it is this.
Towards
an Imperial Solution?
Is
there a solution to the crisis within the existing exploitative,
oppressive framework? The U.S. economy is in deep crisis, and given the
role it plays in the world economy much depends upon it. But U.S.
imperialism continues to control the world’s most powerful, unchallenged
military forces. Can the U.S. ruling elite use its forces to build an
exploitative empire, establish unprecedented political and military
dominance over the world, and in the process manage its economic crisis?
In fact, current U.S. policy is an attempt to do just that.
To
contain the explosion in the U.S. current account deficit, imports need to
be reduced. One way is to reduce such key imports as motor vehicles and
electronic goods by increasing their cost in U.S. dollars through a
revaluation of the yen and the renminbi. This can only be achieved by
political pressure, and it is being applied. Other substantial imports,
such as clothing and footwear, cannot be reduced in quantity since U.S.
producers no longer exist to supply the amount needed. Here costs can be
contained by the relentless imposition of a “race to the bottom”—the
continual transfer of production to ever poorer and more desperate
countries. Here some military force works wonders in enforcing neoliberal
immiseration; consider the results of U.S. intervention in Nicaragua and
Africa. But the key import is mineral fuels, and here the long-term cost
can only be contained by U.S. control of the physical resources. The hand
on the spigot that regulates production (and therefore price) must be
controlled by the United States. This is one aspect of the economic
benefits of U.S. global political power sought through military strength.
The
other aspect of any strategy to contain the unsustainable growth in the
current account deficit needs to be an expansion of U.S. exports. Yet with
the U.S. manufacturing base in terminal decline, only the prospect of
monopoly prices for “intellectual property” offers hope. Here too the
imposition of monopoly prices for the licenses, genetically modified seeds,
pharmaceuticals, songs and movies, is a matter purely of political power
based on military strength.
But
how can this imperialist project be financed? The costs of U.S. military
expansion are likely to aggravate rather than alleviate the U.S. economic
crisis. Stephen Roach of Morgan Stanley asks the question: “Can a saving-short
US economy continue to finance an ever-widening expansion of its military
superiority?” His answer is: “The confluence of history, geopolitics,
and economics leaves me more convinced than ever that a US-centric world
is on an unsustainable path.”12
Could
the U.S. military expansion be financed by the expansion itself? Andy Xie
of Morgan Stanley estimated that the direct and indirect effects of the
U.S. occupation of Iraq could save the United States $40 billion a year in
expenditures on oil imports.13
Assuming these “benefits” are fully realized, that is only a fraction
of the U.S. current account deficits.
But
faced with the increasingly pervasive popular resistance in Iraq, the
United States has not yet been able to realize any of these projected “benefits.”
Months after the so-called “major combat operations” ended and despite
the fact that the United States has committed half of its entire regular
army in Iraq, the United States is losing its grip on Iraq, unable to
control the roads and borders, the water, and the electricity supply.
Out
of the U.S. Army’s thirty-three combat brigades, sixteen are now in Iraq,
two are in Afghanistan, two are in South Korea, and one is in Kosovo. Of
the twelve brigades in the United States, three are in modernization
training, three are in reserve for possible war in Korea, and two are
going to relieve the troops in Afghanistan. There are only four brigades
left to relieve the sixteen brigades in Iraq. In effect, the United States
has exhausted its entire regular army just to occupy such totally
impoverished third world countries as Afghanistan and Iraq.
Whatever
the economic “costs” or “benefits,” U.S. imperialism is losing the
political and ideological battle. According to the latest survey of the
Pew Global Attitudes Project (based in Washington), “America’s image
around the world has taken a sharp turn for the worse.”14
The project of a U.S. global neoliberal empire based on force has
already failed. Not because of internal limits in the working of
capitalism alone, but because the attempt to avoid the economic crisis
that neoliberal policies produce through global military dominance has
already come up against its limits in popular resistance in Iraq. The
crisis of neoliberalism shall follow.
Towards
Social Democracy?
What
will the post-neoliberal world look like? One possibility is a return to
social democratic capitalism. Between 1950 and 1973, with social
democratic institutions such as big government, Keynesianism, class
compromise, redistribution of income and wealth, and regulation of
capital, world capitalism experienced the great “golden age.” For a
quarter of a century, the leading capitalist countries enjoyed rapid
economic growth, low unemployment, rising living standards, and social
stability. Peripheral and semiperipheral states were able to make some
progress in national development through “import-substitution” or
“socialist” industrialization. Could a return to social democracy
bring about a return of the great golden age?
The
inherent contradictions of capitalism did not stop developing under social
democratic capitalism. Within certain limits, the social democratic
institutions helped to alleviate the class conflicts and maintain a
relatively high level of aggregate demand. Under certain historical
conditions, these institutions were consistent with high and stable profit
rates and facilitated rapid capital accumulation. However, as these
institutions existed and operated, they tended to create new conditions
that increasingly undermined worldwide accumulation. The changing balance
of power between capital and labor, and between the core and the periphery
resulted in the worldwide decline of profitability and contributed to the
accumulation crisis in the 1960s and the 1970s.15
It was exactly in response to the crisis of social democratic capitalism
that the global ruling elites started to pursue neoliberalism as the
“solution” to the crisis.
Suppose
the current crisis is to be resolved on a social democratic basis.
National regulations of trade and capital flows are reintroduced, labor
and financial markets are reregulated, income and wealth are significantly
redistributed in egalitarian ways, and the public sector is again to play
a significant role in the economy. Will these changes be sufficient to
bring about a new golden age? Without changing the fundamental
institutions of capitalism, what is to prevent the inherent contradictions
of capitalism from developing? What is to prevent the “new” social
democratic capitalism from entering into a new accumulation crisis?
The
establishment of social democratic capitalism could not take place without
at least a partial political victory of the working classes. But if that
turns out to be the case, the working classes in different parts of the
world will demand not only restoring their historical social and economic
rights and consolidating their existing rights, but also greatly expanding
these rights. How can these new social reforms be financed? If they have
to be financed by additional taxes on capitalist profits, can the revival
of social democracy survive the revival of the working classes’
bargaining power? The growth rates of the post-Second World War golden age
were an exception to the stagnation that characterizes global capitalism
in its monopoly phase. Absent such growth rates, no social democratic
capitalism is possible.
There
are other problems that a revived social democratic capitalism would not
be able to address. Can social democratic capitalism provide the necessary
institutional framework for dealing with the global environmental crisis?
Environmental investment and regulations increase the overall costs of
capitalist production (this is not to be confused with the fact that
environmental businesses may create profit opportunities for some
individual capitalists). There is the question whether after taking full
account of environmental costs, the remaining profits would be sufficient
to induce an adequate level of accumulation. But more likely, in a
capitalist world economy with nation states, the competition between
different capitalist states will prevent them from taking full account of
environmental costs. In that case, social democratic capitalism will
simply be an “alternative” way towards global ecological catastrophe.
Reevaluating
Socialism
Marx
said that the historical justification of capitalism was to develop the
forces of production. Capitalism has clearly succeeded in the development
of the forces of production. It has also succeeded in bringing about
material prosperity for the top 15–20 percent of the world population.
However, it has decisively failed to meet the basic physical and emotional
needs of the great majority of human beings that live in the periphery and
the semiperiphery. In fact, Immanuel Wallerstein questioned whether there
has been any improvement of quality of life for the poorer majority of the
world population since the beginning of the capitalist world economy.16
During
the twentieth century, human beings twice went through the horrific
catastrophes of imperialist wars that arose out of the fundamental
contradictions of capitalism. The past quarter of a century was another
dark age in human history. Under neoliberalism, inequality, oppression,
and exploitation have reached new extremes. In the meantime, under
capitalism humanity is rapidly approaching a global ecological catastrophe.
In
the light of the enormous social and economic disasters brought about by
neoliberalism, it is necessary to reevaluate the historical experience of
socialism. Ten to fifteen years ago, the experience of state socialism in
the former Soviet Union, Eastern Europe, China, and Cuba was generally
considered to be a great failure. In addition to their undemocratic
features, the state socialist societies were believed to have failed
because they were not able to match capitalism in terms of efficiency and
technical innovation. For a while, many have attempted to design new,
“viable” models of socialism. Many of these models intend to be as
efficient as capitalism by incorporating such capitalist features as
markets, competition, and private incentives.
Now
few would doubt that the majority of the Soviet and Eastern European
people lived much better lives under state socialism than under the
present “free” and “democratic” capitalism. Even in China, where
the economy has been the most dynamic in the world, capitalist reforms
since the early 1990s have substantially reduced the living standards of
the peasants and the urban working class, so that in many respects (health
care, education, job security, and workplace conditions), a significant
portion of the Chinese working people now have lower living standards than
during the Maoist era.
The
historical achievements of state socialism should not be under-estimated.
The accomplishment of full employment and job security (freedom from the
fear of unemployment) for all capable adults, men and women, was of
enormous importance. It is well known that state socialist countries had
been more successful in meeting people’s basic needs (nutrition, health
care, education, housing, and pensions) and improving women’s conditions
than capitalist countries with similar levels of economic development.
Soviet, Eastern European, and Cuban socialism had succeeded in meeting
virtually all basic social needs, an achievement that most of the advanced
capitalist countries cannot claim.
What
will be the relevance of socialism for today’s struggle against
neoliberalism? As the crisis of neoliberalism deepens, in many peripheral
and semiperipheral states (such as in Latin America), the situation has
developed to the point that without a complete break with international
finance capital, the imperialist states, and the international
institutions that represent their interests, there are simply no resources
left (after paying a significant portion of the national output each year
to international finance capital) for even simple reproduction of the
society, not to say to address grave social problems. In this situation,
the only sensible solution that is in the interest of the majority of the
people is to make a complete break with the existing international
capitalist order. The national economy needs to be restructured so that
resources are redirected towards production for basic needs rather than
organizing the national economy around exports to the core countries,
under conditions of unequal exchange, in order to import luxury consumer
goods for the privileged elites and the means of production that are used
to reproduce the existing pattern of the international division of labor,
generating “trade surpluses” to serve debt payments and finance
capital flight. But these arrangements will inevitably have conflicts with
the interests of the big financial and industrial capitalists. At some
point, nationalization of the major means of production and the
development of a comprehensive economic plan will have to be pursued for
the economic and social transformation to be sustained.
In
the former Soviet Union, Eastern Europe, and China the corrupt capitalist
privatization processes are extremely unpopular. Should new social
revolutions take place, one can expect the renationalization of all the
illegally privatized assets to be among the top popular demands. The
renationalized assets then would form the basis of a new socialist economy.
The revival of socialism in the periphery and the semiperiphery may set in
motion a new wave of world socialist revolutions.
Can
the next round of socialist revolutions do better than the twentieth
century revolutions? In what way can socialism prove itself to be better
than capitalism? Summarizing the historical lessons of Soviet socialism,
David Kotz argues that, in purely economic terms, centrally planned state
socialism was a viable system. The Soviet system disintegrated because a
procapitalist political alliance (including the majority of the
bureaucratic elite) arose and gained power. Kotz suggests that for a
future socialism to be viable, it must have a democratic state and other
institutions that prevent the development of a privileged and dominant
elite.17
Provided
that a future socialist society will be based on political democracy, how
will a future socialist economy be organized and structured? In addition
to many existing theoretical contributions on the subject, future
socialist movements will certainly be able to develop a great variety of
new institutions, new practices in actual historical struggles. Ultimately,
the future socialist economy has to be organized in such a way that it is
capable of addressing the historical contradictions to which capitalism
has failed to provide a solution.
Given
the historical record of state socialism, one can have great confidence
that an economic system based on primarily public ownership of the means
of production and democratic planning (democratic control over the
allocation of the social surplus) will have a great chance to succeed in
meeting the basic needs of all members of society. If this can be achieved,
then at the very least, socialism will bring about a better material life
for the poorest 60–70 percent of the population in the world, whose
basic needs have never been met under capitalism.
Socialism
offers the best hope for humanity to avoid global ecological catastrophe
and to build harmonious relationships between human beings and our
environment. In this respect, the record of state socialism was not
favorable. But the record needs to be understood in its historical context.
In addition to the bureaucratic, undemocratic nature of state socialist
planning, state socialist societies were forced to engage in military and
economic competition against hostile capitalist powers. Given the context,
they were forced to sacrifice everything in order to “develop the forces
of production.”
The
hope is that the future socialist society will have better, generally
benign external environments (if there is not going to be a world
socialist government). In that case, there will not be external pressures
to force future socialism to develop the forces of production rapidly and
in an unbalanced fashion. Given the arrangements of political democracy
and socialist planning, people in these societies will be able to debate
and decide, based on their own preferences, how much surplus they would
like to generate as well as determine how the surplus should be allocated.
The need to have a sustainable environment, through democratic processes,
will be understood by the general public, and will be reflected in the
planning, balanced against other needs and desires, including the desire
for material comfort. Unless one believes that people will always be
capitalist minded, always wanting more regardless of how that affects
future generations, then it seems that sustaining the environment in which
human beings live would certainly become one of the paramount objectives
of future socialist planning.